Yamini Aiyar Asks a Question, and We Try to Answer

First, the question. We’ll get to who the “we” in the title is (or should it be “are” instead of “is”?) in a bit, and also to our answers.

Ideally in a democracy, there ought to be space for evidence-based partnerships with government whilst simultaneously holding the mirror. But when the space for holding the mirror shrinks, when freedoms are trampled upon, what should the public policy professional do? There is a real risk that the pressures of relevance can, and indeed do, push researchers to blunt critique, to inadvertently, perhaps, stop asking difficult questions and refrain from critical public engagement. Is there a need then to redefine our role, to question the narrow prism of relevance and impact that we judge ourselves by?

https://www.deccanherald.com/opinion/on-evidence-policy-making-and-critiquing-it-in-a-polarised-polity-2958920

Say Hello to ArreBhaiWah

Paul Krugman has a textbook on international economics. Standard stuff, and quite a good textbook, running into multiple editions. I may be wrong over here about the specific topic, but I think it is in the context of national accounting with international trade that Paul Krugman asks us to imagine a country called Agraria.

In much the same vein, but for entirely different reasons, I’m going to ask you to imagine a country called ArreBhaiWah.

Because when it comes to India, we will have to spend a significant amount of time having heated debates about whether the space for holding the mirror has shrunk or not. I might (and do!) say that yes, it has shrunk. You, on the other hand, might say that it has expanded instead. And then we will argue and call each other names and get applauded for having reminded the other side of their grandmothers. That is fun to do, but would not be constructive, nor productive.

So let us, instead, focus on ArreBhaiWah.


If you are a public policy professional in ArreBhaiWah, and you see that the space for holding the mirror has shrunk, and you need to analyze what you should do about it – what framework should you use to arrive at your answer?

This isn’t about answering the question for ArreBhaiWah, you see. As with many posts on EFE, it is about supplying you with a framework to think about the problem. Please decide for yourselves whether the question makes sense, is applicable and finally, what your answer (if any) should be.

Which brings us to who the “we” in the title of this post are (or should it be “is” instead of “are”?). It is yours truly, and the late, great A.O. Hirschman. By the way, both Yamini’s piece and this Wikipedia article about Hirschman deserve to be read in their entirety, so please do.

Exit, Loyalty and Voice

Here’s ChatGPT’s summary of one of my favorite books in economics:

“Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States” is a seminal book by Albert O. Hirschman, published in 1970. The work presents a framework for understanding how people respond to dissatisfaction with organizations or states they are part of. Hirschman’s theory is built around three main concepts: exit, voice, and loyalty, which are mechanisms through which individuals can express their discontent and potentially influence change.

Exit: The option of leaving the organization or ceasing to use its products or services. This is a common response in economic markets; for example, if a customer is dissatisfied with a product, they can simply stop buying it and switch to a competitor. Exit is a powerful mechanism in promoting quality and efficiency due to the competitive pressure it creates.

Voice: The option of actively expressing dissatisfaction and seeking to improve conditions from within, rather than leaving. Voice can take many forms, including direct feedback, protests, or any attempt to change the organization’s practices or policies. Voice is particularly relevant in scenarios where exit is not feasible or desirable, such as in monopolies or with state governance.

Loyalty: Loyalty plays a moderating role in the exit and voice framework. It refers to a person’s attachment to an organization, leading them to endure dissatisfaction while trying to improve the organization through voice, rather than exiting. Loyalty can delay exit and give voice a chance to work, as loyal members or customers may seek to solve problems internally rather than abandoning the organization.

Hirschman’s framework is used to analyze a wide range of economic, political, and social phenomena. It provides insights into how organizations and states can deteriorate or improve over time based on the feedback mechanisms available to and utilized by their members or constituents. It also highlights the importance of maintaining the right balance between allowing exit and encouraging voice to ensure the health and adaptability of organizations and societies.

ChatGPT4

And this is an excellent framework with which to answer Yamini’s question: in ArreBhaiWah, what should the public policy professional do?

Should they choose exit, or voice? To what extent should loyalty influence your decision? Remember, loyalty refers to a person’s attachment to the organization (or the entity) in question.

This is where I step in.


What Are you Optimizing For?

  1. Should you be optimizing for what is best for you?
    • Best for you in a professional context, or personal context?
    • Best for your conscience, or best for your career?
  2. Or should you be optimizing for what is best for ArreBhaiWah?
  3. Or should you be optimizing for what is best for the folks who currently run the government in ArreBhaiWah?

Because as Khyati Pathak, Pranay Kotasthane and Anupam Manur point out in their excellent book We, the Citizens:

Source: We, The Citizens, pg 19

So is your loyalty to the government, or to the nation? Or are you of the considered opinion that the two are the same thing? They are manifestly not, by the way, so even if it is your considered opinion that they are the same thing, please do read Chapter 2 from the book, We, The Citizens (and the rest of the book, while you are at it!)


As with everything else in life, there are only trade-offs, and no solutions. There isn’t an easy way to answer this question that Yamini asks, alas. Optimizing for any one of oneself, ArreBhaiWah or its government also implies not optimizing for everything else.

But there you have it: the framework that one should use while thinking about the answer to Yamini’s question in the context of ArreBhaiWah.


What should her answer be, you ask? Why, that is Yamini’s business and no one else’s, surely. Allow me to wish her luck for what lies ahead, and to thank her for her work thus far. You and I may have disagreed with her about some of her conclusions, but that, I would argue, was part of the point.

Voice is currently underrated!

Were The Farm Laws a “1991 Moment”?

As with everything that happens in the world today, so also with the farm laws: a lot of heat, and hardly any light. Reams have been written about how the farm laws were good (or bad), about their introduction being a much needed thing (or not), and their withdrawal being a disaster for take-your-pick-from-Modi-BJP-India (or not).

I have neither the desire nor the energy to get into any of these debates. Here’s my simple take as a student of economics: markets almost always work. Where they don’t work, identify the reasons why they don’t work, and either correct those causal factors, or have the government step in until (and only until) those factors are corrected.

Things get tricky when you begin to ask pesky questions along these lines:

  • How do you define markets not working? Bench-marked against what standard? Who decides?
  • How do you correct these causal factors? How do you judge that they have been corrected? Are you sure they won’t return? On what basis?
  • To what extent should government step in? How are you sure this will make things better in all markets at all points of time? Using what framework?

But that is precisely what makes the study of India’s political economy so very interesting! And this is true of agriculture as well, not just in India, but in other places too.


For the moment, let’s take as a given the fact that government had to be present in agricultural markets in India these past decades. That may or may not be true, but for the purposes of this blog post, let us assume that there was a confluence of factors in India’s agricultural markets that necessitated the active presence of the government as a participant, not just as a regulator.

Now, if markets almost always work, and if government was present in agriculture, then we have to figure out a way for government to eventually not be present in agriculture. (Note, again, that your opinion may be different from mine. But play along with me for the moment, please.)


Yamini Aiyar and Mekhala Krishnamurthy argue in an HT article that in the case of the three farm laws, what the government missed out on was the word “eventually”. They argue that it was the suddenness of the move that was problematic, not the move itself.

There’s a political angle to the sudden withdrawal, and the authors refer to it in their piece. There’s a regulatory angle to the sudden withdrawal, and that is also covered by the authors. But there also is an institutional (and therefore economic) angle to it, and that is what I would like to focus on:

Consider this. The protesting farmers from Punjab, Haryana and western Uttar Pradesh are locked into a system where State intervention, driven by the logic of Minimum Support Prices (MSP) and the Agricultural Produce Marketing Committee (APMC) mandis, dominates. The State is not a benign actor. It has created and sustained local elites with vested interests – traders, middlemen and moneylenders, each of whom extracts to control market power. This undermines competition and compromises farmer interests in different ways. But farmers have learnt to negotiate these relationships of extraction. And the state through MSP and mandis has served as insurance that gives them bargaining power. Any attempt to break this system will inevitably, as the protests amply demonstrate, unleash anxieties.
In this context, the move towards genuine competition will not be viable without the State demonstrating its willingness to protect farmers interests and gain their trust.

https://twitter.com/AiyarYamini/status/1464452741325996032/photo/1

What is the point? The point is that the current system isn’t perfect, and it isn’t sustainable. As the authors point out, the farming sector isn’t competitive.

In theory, that should mean, to a student of economics, that they are not efficient. That, in turn, means that we should expect that producers aren’t producing as much as they could have, and whatever they produce is being produced at a higher cost than would otherwise have been the case. We should expect that procurement, storage and distribution are also potentially riddled with inefficiencies. We should expect divergent quality of produce, and we should expect consumers to be paying higher prices, potentially for a lower variety of goods.

We should also anticipate a whole host of things due to the fact that the farming sector isn’t competitive: prices aren’t transparently determined, there isn’t free entry and exit, certain sellers are likely to get a better deal, transaction and search costs are high, and on and on and on. This is microeconomics 101 in practice.

(A quick note to students of economics: ask yourself if you’re able to relate what you’re learning in your microeconomics courses to the two paragraphs above. If you disagree with my assessment, ask yourself what is it that is causing you to disagree. Can you frame your disagreement in the context of microeconomic theory? Secondly, irrespective of whether you agree or not, can you think of what data points you might need to empirically verify or disprove my arguments? Where might these data points be available? What models (economic and econometric) can we use to settle this debate? Finally, why stop at agricultural markets – which other markets can you analyze this way?)

And for all of these reasons and more, reform is needed. It cannot possibly be anybody’s argument that the status quo in India’s agriculture must persist forever.


Which then, in turn, gives rise to two separate questions:

  1. If reforms are to be introduced, how?
  2. However they are to be introduced, how fast should we proceed with their implementation?

Again, the question isn’t one of the desirability of reforms, or their appropriateness. Rather, the question is about whether the reforms should be a top-down, one-size-fits-all initiative, or a more locally driven approach. And second, should reforms be introduced all at once, or slowly and gradually, one step at a time.

And I would like to argue that at least in this one regard, we should be looking at China. Not for the specifics of their reform and a CTRL-C CTRL-V hit job. But for their approach, beginning in the late 1970’s.


When I first proposed the household responsibility system (HRS), I was criticized as follows: Chairman Mao had been dead only a few years. Supporting the HRS, a system he opposed, meant forsaking his principles. This was the severe environment that reform faced at first. Our support of the HRS, of institutional innovation, and of transformation of the agents of the rural microeconomy would inevitably involve adjusting a number of interests. To avoid risk, it was necessary to carry out trials first. Also, the HRS could not move ahead on its own. It had do so in connection with other institutions and be realized in the course of reforming the institutional environment as a whole. But this institutional reform is not something that could be accomplished in one fell swoop. To carry out reform, a strategy of gradual advance was unavoidable.

http://ebrary.ifpri.org/utils/getfile/collection/p15738coll2/id/125214/filename/125215.pdf (Emphasis added)

That’s Du Runsheng, the author of a short publication called The Course of China’s Rural Reform. He did, um, some other things besides.

In the publication that I have excerpted from above, there are some points that I am going to summarize that I think help me make my point better:

  1. Resistance to the introduction of market based reforms was anticipated in China back then, and was in some sense inevitable. Three measures were conceived of to reduce this resistance:
    1. “First, the reform would not initially call for abandoning the people’s communes, but rather would implement a production responsibility system within them. This approach enabled many who would have opposed the change to accept it.”
    2. “Second, the responsibility system could take a number of forms, among which the populace could choose. One did not impose one’s own subjective preference on the populace but respected its choice.”
    3. “Third, the reform began in a limited region, where it received popular support, and then widened step by step.” (Emphasis added)
  2. “In 1980, after the central leadership was reorganized on a collective basis, the top central leaders, including Deng Xiaoping and Hu Yaobang, consistently supported allowing different areas to adopt different forms of the agricultural production responsibility system. It was then proposed to divide them into three types of areas: impoverished areas would carry out the HRS; advanced ones would adopt specialized contracts with wages linked to output; and intermediate regions could freely choose.”
  3. Or, as Ajay Shah and Vijay Kelkar put it in their book:
    “The heterogeneity of economic and social development, across the regions of India, generates heterogeneity in the public policy pathways desired by different groups of people. A policy position that is well liked in Uttar Pradesh may not be liked in Kerala, and vice versa. This creates conflict in a centralized public policy process.”
    Kelkar, Vijay; Shah, Ajay. In Service of the Republic . Penguin Random House India Private Limited. Kindle Edition.
  4. Finally, there’s a lot to pick at and think about here when we get down to the specifics. I’m not suggesting that China in the late 1970’s had the exact same problems that India does today. Nor am I suggesting that India do today exactly what China did back then. I am making three points:
    1. I agree with Yamini Aiyar and Mekhala Krishnamurthy when they say that one of the problems was the suddenness of the proposed reforms, both in terms of their scope, and in terms of their geographical spread. I also agree with them when they say that the introduction of the reforms ignored the ground realities of the both the sociology of agricultural markets, and their institutional complexity (note that I am paraphrasing here, these are not their words).
    2. But having read their article, one must ask: if not the pathway that we have now left behind us, what else? That is, for better or for worse, the three farm laws now stand withdrawn. Is the status quo desirable? Should we seek to perpetuate it, or change it for “the better”? (Inverted quotes because better means different things to different people.) My opinion is that we should seek to change it for the better, and maybe yours is the same.
    3. But that gives rise to the next question: how? And that is where Du Runsheng and his write-up is of limited help. Learning how other nations did it is a good place to start if you are a student of economics, India or public policy, and post-Mao China holds some valuable lessons for us.